Peter Josty is Executive Director of the Centre for Innovation Studies in Calgary.
Canada has a big productivity problem. The current approach to tackle this is to double down on the supply side (i.e. producing technology) rather than the demand side (i.e. diffusing technology throughout the economy). That is a mistake.
The productivity problem is well known. Canada’s productivity has fallen to 73.3 per cent of the U.S. rate, down from over 90 per cent in the 1980s.
Why does this matter? First of all, productivity is needed to maintain our standard of living. Secondly, there are several looming areas where we will have to spend a lot more money in future decades – healthcare (for the aging population), the military (for the deteriorating geopolitical situation) and climate change. Higher productivity will enable this spending.
Most of Canada’s large support programs for innovation are currently on the supply side – Scientific Research and Experimental Development (SR&ED) tax credit, Global Innovation Clusters, and the now postponed Canada Innovation Corporation.
Lack of attention to demand side of innovation
The lack of attention to the demand side of innovation has been pointed out in a number of reports:
It has been well documented that while we pay most attention to the generation of technology, it is its diffusion through the economy that really creates the economic impact.
Why do we need a fresh approach?
We have to face up to the fact that our current approach to innovation policy isn’t working, and we have to try something new. Here are some facts:
A useful framework for combining supply side and demand side thinking about this is provided by Neil Lee in his book, Innovation for the Masses. He sees three types of institution being needed for a successful economy:
Generative Institutions – those that create new technologies – for example: universities, science parks, incubators and accelerators, venture capital, government funding of leading sectors, angel investors, R&D tax credits, patent agents.
Diffusive Institutions – those that spread technology through the economy – for example: networks of small firms, vocational skills systems, worker training, business networks that help diffuse technologies, a competitive marketplace, government procurement, agricultural extension offices, standard setting.
Redistributive Institutions – those that offset some of the inequality effects of new technologies – for example: minimum wages, progressive taxation, welfare state.
What are the solutions?
The key, according to Lee, is to have an appropriate balance between the three kinds of institution – generative, diffusive and distributive. Canada already has reasonable generative institutions – with strong showing in academic papers. It has good redistributive institutions, but the country has relatively weak diffusive institutions. So we need to strengthen the distributive institutions.
One of the most powerful ways to incentivize diffusion of technology throughout the economy is to make Canada’s economy more competitive. Companies would be forced to adopt new technologies and become more competitive to stay in business.
A wide variety of other approaches have been proposed:
Conclusion
Canada needs to strengthen its diffusive institutions to accelerate the diffusion of new technology through the economy. This will create a better balance between generative, diffusive and distributive institutions – and lead to better productivity.
R$